Jones D (2021) Barbarigenesis and the collapse of complex societies: Rome and after. PLoS ONE 16(9): e0254240, Sep 16 2021. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0254240
Abstract: “Barbarism” is perhaps best understood as a recurring syndrome among peripheral societies in response to the threats and opportunities presented by more developed neighbors. This article develops a mathematical model of barbarigenesis—the formation of “barbarian” societies adjacent to more complex societies—and its consequences, and applies the model to the case of Europe in the first millennium CE. A starting point is a game (developed by Hirshleifer) in which two players allocate their resources either to producing wealth or to fighting over wealth. The paradoxical result is that a richer and potentially more powerful player may lose out to a poorer player, because the opportunity cost of fighting is greater for the former. In a more elaborate spatial model with many players, the outcome is a wealth-power mismatch: central regions have comparatively more wealth than power, peripheral regions have comparatively more power than wealth. In a model of historical dynamics, a wealth-power mismatch generates a long-lasting decline in social complexity, sweeping from more to less developed regions, until wealth and power come to be more closely aligned. This article reviews how well this model fits the historical record of late Antiquity and the early Middle Ages in Europe both quantitatively and qualitatively. The article also considers some of the history left out of the model, and why the model doesn’t apply to the modern world.
Opportunity costs
So far we have been considering what happened. But our model also implies something about how it happened, how a relatively small number of barbarians had an oversized impact. Specifically, in the model, the greater resources available to folk in the core under imperial rule are counterbalanced by their greater opportunity cost of fighting. This seems to be consistent with several scholarly analyses.
The Roman Empire simply became too expensive for its inhabitants, who were no longer willing to pay in blood and money for its military power [57].
Measuring resources by population and economic production, the core had a great advantage over its neighboring periphery. “There can be little doubt that the empire possessed considerably greater reserves of manpower than the barbarians” [58]. In the fifth century, when the Roman Empire fell in the west, “historians generally propose up to 100,000 for major ruling groups like the Ostrogoths or the Vandals, and around 20,000–25,000 for the adult males who made up their armies, in provinces whose indigenous populations numbered in the millions” [42]; also [57]. There were similar disproportions in the sixth century, when much of Italy fell to the Lombards, and in the ninth and tenth centuries, when Vikings raided and settled in northern Europe. Even where the barbarian fraction was arguably greater—Franks in north Gaul, Angles, Saxons, and Jutes in Britain, Slavs in the Balkans—they were still in the minority.
In other words, if all parties had realized their full military potential and put all their economic surplus into fighting, the imperial core would easily have come out ahead. But recall the paradox of power: “the battle is not always to the strong [because] in a wide range of circumstances it pays the smaller or weaker contender to fight harder” [19]. Applied to the present case, the paradox implies that what determined outcomes in the contest between rich core and poor periphery was not just the absolute resources of each, but the opportunity costs of fighting and preparing to fight.
Economic concerns were central both in imperial expansion and contraction, even if the parties involved were not keeping careful accounts, or undertaking explicit profit maximization. “The Roman emperors had at least a crude sense of the ‘marginal costs of imperialism’” [27]. When the Roman empire was expanding, the dates at which different regions were incorporated into the empire corresponded with their economic potential (Fig 6).
During periods of decline as well, considerations of costs and benefits were crucial. The Roman military suffered some major defeats, notably at Adrianople (378 CE) where the emperor Valens and two thirds of his army perished. But the more fundamental cause of the fall is that the cost of defense came to exceed what people were willing to pay. Already under the Dominate the empire offered less bang for more bucks: citizens found themselves paying higher taxes and (probably) getting less military protection. Contrary to earlier views [59], high taxes and bureaucracy do not seem to have crippled the economy, but they did undermine support for the empire [58].
In the late third and fourth centuries, the empire confronted multiple invasions, from Visigoths, Ostrogoths, Vandals, Suevi, Alans, Burgundians, and Franks. The invaders were sometimes bought off with grants of territory and a status as foederati; more often they forcibly seized what they wanted. In any case, when territory ravaged or occupied by barbarians was lost as a source of revenue, the army could no longer be paid. In less than a century the Roman empire in the West unraveled completely. After two more centuries, the empire in southeastern Europe unraveled. No decisive battle ended the empire; it became unaffordable [51].
Even after the collapse of imperial rule the old Roman elite did not just disappear: some were killed, some fled, but others remained and adapted to the new regimes. Some even flourished, although on terms dictated by their new barbarian overlords [60].
Different scholars offer differing assessments of Roman-barbarian relations in the transition. On one account, it was mostly about the art of the deal: “What we call the Fall of the Roman empire was an imaginative experiment that got a little out of hand” [61]. A more somber judgment comes from Ward-Perkins [34]: “The Germanic invaders of the Western empire seized or extorted through the threat of force the vast majority of the territories in which they settled, without any formal agreement on how to share resources with their new Roman subjects.” From our perspective, these quotations point to flip sides of the paradox of power. On one side, the paradox implies that “non-conflictual or cooperative strategies tend to be relatively more rewarding for the better-endowed side” [19], and the Roman empire, Roman elites after the fall, and Roman successor states, all showed themselves willing sometimes to bargain and collaborate with barbarian intruders. On the other side, violence and the threat of violence from those with less to lose played a determining role in the transition. The game between Romans and barbarians was not zero-sum, but it was a long way from purely cooperative.
Varieties of rent-seeking: States and migrations
Our model predicts that where there is a wealth-power mismatch between core and periphery, there will be rent seeking. The exact mechanisms are not specified by the model, but they included, at different periods, shifts in power and wealth within the Roman empire, raiding and plunder, the consolidation of barbarian confederations and kingdoms, and barbarian invasion, migration, and mass settlement. We review varieties of rent-seeking below.
Our model implies that even in the early stages, when collateral damage is slight, we should see evidence of wealth-power mismatch. In the context of the early centuries CE, this means we expect to find a mismatch within the Empire, with more developed regions increasingly specializing in producing wealth and less developed regions increasingly cultivating a military specialization.
Even before the establishment of the Principate, this dynamic was at work, as Rome extended her rule over the Mediterranean. During this period, the eastern Mediterranean, ruled by Hellenistic monarchs, was more economically developed than the Roman West. This both made the area an inviting target for conquest, and contributed to military weakness: Eastern militaries were largely mercenary, and expensive. Rome at this point depended on a cheaper army of citizen soldiers [62, 63].
With the establishment of the Principate, the military basis of the empire shifted to a professional soldiery committed especially to defending the frontier, often relatively removed from the civilian population. About 2/3 of state revenues, some 2–3% of gross domestic product, went to the military [27]. About half the army consisted of citizen legionaries, about half of auxiliary forces, mostly non-citizens. The regular army increasingly drew its men from the provinces, outside Italy and the more developed east.
[M]ost legionaries across the empire were of Italian origin until the reign of Claudius (AD 41–54). Through the reigns of Claudius and Nero, about half were Italian and half of provincial origin. By Trajan’s reign (AD 98–117), legionnaires from the provinces outnumbered Italians by four or five to one [64].
The auxiliary forces too came to be largely drawn from the provinces: “It is by the blood of the provinces that the provinces are won” (Tacitus in [65]).
Barbarians may have come to make up an increasing fraction of the military [66, 67], (but see [68]). “The spatial, social, and ethnic peripheralization of military service—a feature common to many maturing empires—not only raised the profile of frontier forces but also drew in manpower from beyond” [63]. They became increasingly numerous in the higher ranks. “By the latter half of the fourth century increasing numbers of senior officers appear with ‘barbarian,’ frequently Germanic names” [69]. In the last days of the empire in the west, supreme military command increasingly passed to generals of Germanic origin, like Arbogast, a Frank, and Stilicho, a Vandal.
Political changes accompanied the demilitarization of the imperial core and the militarization of the periphery. Emperors from Trajan and Hadrian on found themselves spending increasing amounts of time close to the frontier, and the effective capitol shifted from Rome to Milan (286 CE) and then to Ravenna (402 CE). The old Senatorial elite of Italy, the clarissimi, continued to be extremely wealthy, but were edged out politically by a new senatorial elite. The crisis of the third century and subsequent recovery partly reflected these changes. In the third century, military units on the frontiers vied with Rome, putting up a bewildering succession of barracks emperors. Eventually a more settled situation developed as one frontier region, Illyria, came to monopolize the imperial succession.
These changes within the empire can be seen as the working out of the principle of comparative advantage, with more and less developed regions coming to specialize in production and fighting respectively. This was not the conventional, peaceable version of comparative advantage. These developments, resulting from wealth-power mismatch, were about rent-seeking: capturing wealth and forestalling its capture.
In subsequent centuries, with barbarian resources increasing outside the empire, barbarian rent seeking, trading on barbarian military prowess, is increasingly evident. This took a variety of forms. Military service, raiding and plunder, and the extortion of tribute, carried out by barbarian groups of various sizes at the expense of wealthier targets, are amply attested before and after the fall of Rome. There were also changes in social organization. Barbarian polities along the frontier probably increased their size and degree of organization, and grew more formidable. “There are clear signs that some barbarian units, especially just beyond the frontier were increasing in power and stability during the fourth century” [58]. Larger groupings appearing in the early centuries CE include the Franks (“Free/wild people”), Marcomanni (“Border men”), and Alamanni (“All men”) [57]. These changes arguably resulted from the pressures and opportunities associated with proximity to a wealthy core. The changes were driven by trade and combat—offensive and defensive—with the Roman empire itself, and jostling among barbarians for access to imperial resources. They amounted, in short, to a phase of barbarigenesis. (This outline is widely but not universally accepted, see [18, 57, 58, 70, 71], but see also [69] and [72]. For a similar story of barbarian agglomeration and civilized response in the Viking age, with a dynamic model, see [73].)
Most dramatically and consequentially, barbarians could secure a share in the wealth of their neighbors by moving to where the wealth was. The first millennium has traditionally been seen as the Migration Period, the age of the Völkerwanderung. Below a few remarks on a large and disputed topic:
First, migrations during this period were mostly toward regions with denser population and greater wealth (with some exceptions, like the Norse settlement of Iceland). Some migrations proceeded from outer periphery to inner periphery. The Goths expanded from the Baltic area (Wielbark archeological culture) to the north shore of the Black Sea (Cernjakov culture) and took up plundering Roman territory on the farther shores. Huns, Avars, and Magyars moved from the Eurasian steppe to the grasslands of the Great Hungarian Plain and took up plundering and extorting tribute from the empire and its territory. Other groups moving from outer to inner periphery at some point include Burgundians, Lombards, and Bulgars. Some migrations proceeded from the periphery to imperial or former imperial territory. Germanic peoples ended up ruling over most of the western empire, southern Slavs took over most of the eastern empire in Europe. Migrations were often interconnected. The early Gothic migration pressured west Germanic groups, the Huns pressured the Goths, and the Avars pressured the southern Slavs. Western Slavs moved into territory vacated by Germanic migrations. Both push and pull might be involved in the initial migration in a series. Avars, for example, were pushed to the western edge of the steppe by Turks. But the pull toward greater wealth stands out as the dominant theme in this period.
Second, the migrations entailed substantial costs. Most of the migrants were not habitual nomads. Moving to a new location, sometimes over very large distances, sometimes more than once, entailed a major reorganization of customary routines. Even for pastoral nomads, large scale moves into new territory were not an everyday occurrence. Migration could also entail challenging political transformations, including submission to new forms of authority.
Third, the migrations arguably involved the movements of large groups of men and women, not just elites or bands of soldiers. At least this is the traditional view [66], consistent with the writings of classical authors like Marcellinus Ammianus and Jordanes. However, this is an area of controversy; Halsall [58], for example, is a skeptic regarding large-scale migrations, while Heather [18] provides a nuanced defense of something closer to the traditional view.
In the future, new sources of evidence, especially studies of genetic variation, will advance this debate. For now, some preliminary results are available. The movement of Goths, including women, from the shores of the Baltic to the Black Sea is supported by genetic evidence [74], consistent with Jordanes, and contra Kulikowski [75] who argued for cultural transformation without major migration. The Anglo-Saxon invasions (unlike the later Norman invasion) had a substantial impact on the genetics of England [76, 77], contra the argument that Anglo-Saxonization involved only limited migration [78]. In sixth century Italy, ancient DNA from high status graves shows the central European affinities expected of Lombard invaders, while low status burials have local roots [79].
Thus the evidence to date suggests that at least some of the migrations of the Völkerwanderung were a real demographic phenomenon—less than population replacement, but more than culture shift. It looks like large groups of men and women from the barbarian periphery of Europe were paying the costs and enjoying the benefits of moving to, or close to, more central societies, and living off them.
Collateral damage
Collateral damage from wealth-power mismatch within the empire was limited and episodic, with a partial recovery following the establishment of a new equilibrium under the Dominate. In a later period, as military advantage shifted further to the barbarians outside the empire, the damage would be increasingly severe and enduring. For the barbarian invaders of the Roman empire, the goal was to acquire Roman wealth, not to destroy it. Nevertheless, without anybody intending it, the first millennium saw a lasting collapse in social complexity and a decline in wealth, resulting to a large extent from the interactions between Europe’s core and its periphery. As in our model, this happened because there was not only rent-seeking, an unproductive diversion of resources into contests, but also collateral damage, a counterproductive loss of resources.
Collateral damage, like rent-seeking, took a variety of forms. It was partly a matter of direct destruction of property and loss of life. Beyond this, the Mediterranean-centered trade network collapsed, and the advantages of a Smithian economy, with an extensive division of labor were lost [39]. Perhaps most important, institutional breakdown and the insecurity of life and property must have discouraged individuals and groups from investing in the future.
The extent of collateral damage varied, depending on the character of political institutions. In some times and places, barbarians acted as stationary bandits [80]. A stationary bandit, in contrast to a roving bandit, has an incentive to preserve the long-term productivity of his targets. The itinerant armies of the Völkerwanderung–the Visigoths shifting around the Balkans, Italy, and Spain, the Suevi and Vandals moving through Gaul and Iberia—approximated roving bandits. By the end of the fifth century, however, these groups had settled down; most of the former Roman empire in the West was divided among a handful of successor states ruled by Germanic elites. Consistent with Olson’s analysis, the new rulers were not purely predatory; they tried to maintain the traditions of Roman rule, and to enlist the collaboration of surviving Roman elites [81]. (See also [82] on the Vikings.)
The situation was complicated, however. The stationary bandits of the post-Roman world were not unitary actors [81]. The new rulers depended on the support of the barbarian rank-and-file, the military mainstay of the new kingdoms. These followers, the descendants of fractious unlettered warrior-farmers, were often unfitted and disinclined to play the role of obedient Roman-style subjects [83]. “[T]he Germanic tribes which broke apart the Western empire were not themselves capable of substituting a new or coherent political universe for it. The difference in ‘water-levels’ between the two civilizations was still too great” [84]. As a result, early barbarian kingdoms were hybrid regimes, with one legal system for Romans, another for Germans, with the latter enjoying a privileged position. The latter were also rewarded with a share of wealth at the expense of the former, either grants of land (the usual scholarly supposition [85, 86]) or a share of taxes [61]. In either case, central revenues were greatly reduced [87]. “Beginning in the fifth century, there was a steady trend away from supporting armies by public taxation and towards supporting them by rents derived from private landowning” [42].
In some cases, the balance between leaders and rank-and-file among the newcomers was weighted heavily toward the latter; enduring royal government was weak or nonexistent. This was particularly true where larger numbers of settlers moved shorter distances, as in Anglo-Saxon Britain, Frankish northern Gaul, and the Slavic Balkans. In these instances, the decay of Roman institutions and the decline in social complexity was particularly marked.
The collapse of social complexity in the first millennium was both cause and consequence of a decline in state capacity, collateral damage from the shift to a low-maintenance political regime that provided limited public order at a low price. “The new Germanic lords could not offer the same extensive administration to the landowners, but they did something else: they provided cheaper protection” [62]. Some early medieval kingdoms look impressive on a map, but “by the year 1000, [outside the Byzantine empire] it would have been difficult to find anything like a state anywhere on the continent in Europe” [88]. Early medieval polities are better described as realms than states [89]. Lasting recovery would wait until the rolling wave of barbarigenesis had subsided.
Political complexities: States, cycles, and borders
The discussion up to this point has related political changes to the operation of large-scale forces over the long run. Shifts in wealth and power within the Roman empire, its dissolution first in the west and then in the European east, the formation of barbarian states, and their relative weakness when it came to maintaining law and order, all resulted, we argue, from the spatial dynamics of wealth-power mismatch, of wealth production and appropriation. But states were not entirely at the mercy of larger forces; they could also be actors in their own right. Some complications resulted that fall outside our model.
In the model, decline and recovery happen smoothly. But internal factors, apart from the external stimuli we have considered so far, also contributed to the relative strength or weakness of states. In some cases these seem to have operated cyclically: the Roman empire in the west from the first to fifth century ran through a progression—stability, near collapse, partial recovery, collapse (see above)–that amounts to two up and down alternations, each lasting a few centuries. This cycle is superimposed on the long downward movement predicted by our model [90]. (The preceding rise and fall of Republican Rome is another up and down alternation.)
Boundaries between states, unrepresented in our model, also made a difference. This may be showing up in Fig 7, where there is a middle set of countries, from Bulgaria to England, for which the model is qualitatively somewhat “off.” Take England. The model predicts modest growth to the mid-first millennium, stagnation as barbarigenesis among the country’s less-developed neighbors takes a toll, and then recovery. The real story is more dramatic, probably even more dramatic, according to later research, than McEvedy and Jones’ figures imply. As part of the Roman Empire from 43 CE, Britain experienced substantial prosperity and security. The withdrawal of Roman legions after 409 CE, followed by invasions from the Continent, resulted in a major—apparently catastrophic—decline in the density of settlement and the level of material culture [91]. “In no other part of the empire was this economic simplification so abrupt and total” [42]. In some respects, the level of material culture in Britain was lower after the legions left than before they arrived! It almost looks like the model is telling a story about an alternative history in which the Romans never occupied Britain. This counterfactual southern Britain, remaining outside the Roman Empire, avoids the wild swing from prosperity to utter collapse of the real-world England. In other words, being inside and then outside the Roman limes made a difference in ways not shown in our model. Similar observations apply to Bulgaria and Yugoslavia, where the later end of Roman rule was particularly devastating, and where, as in England, barbarian invasion led to language replacement. (Also related: in Germany there are differences right up to the present between areas that fell inside and outside the limes [92]).
These complications do not overturn the account given here, but they suggest that our model might usefully be supplemented by models of internally-driven secular cycles [90] and imperiogenesis [9]. These models do not capture the dynamics of barbarigenesis and its consequences that we explore here; they are complementary to the present effort.
Geographic complexities: Rivers and mountains, steppe, and a sheltered zone
Other potential complications left out of our model involve geographic variation. In the Results section we run the model assuming uniform geography, and then look at deviations from the model as a secondary phenomenon. The deviations largely make sense, reflecting the impacts of waterways and mountainous terrain, and the availability of arable land (with Greece as something of a special case).
For much of the rest of Eurasia, the uniform geography assumption wouldn’t work even as a rough first approximation. In the region from the Middle East through Central and South Asia to China, the division between steppe and desert on the one hand and areas of rain-fed and irrigation agriculture on the other hand was a decisive fact. Throughout this expanse, where pastoral nomads had agrarian states for neighbors, barbarigenesis took place, with the emergence of wealth-power mismatches, and the formation of states driven by external threats and opportunities [93–95]. Because the border between periphery and core was the product of a climatically-dictated resource gradient between steppe and sown, the historical dynamics were different here from post-Roman Europe; this is a topic for another occasion.
Finally, where the geography of barbarians and decline and fall is concerned, the fate of the empire in the east seems to be the exception that proves the rule. In the Roman west—as in our model of barbarigenesis—the wealth of the core was up for grabs. In the east, by contrast, most of the core resource base was more secure. The European provinces of the eastern empire experienced a slew of barbarian invasions, by Visigoths (late fourth century), Huns (mid fifth century), and Ostrogoths (late fifth century). As in the west, these resulted in extensive destruction. But most of this area remained under Roman rule for several centuries longer than in the west. A key difference is that the eastern Roman empire was able to draw on the resources of a hinterland in Asia Minor, the Near East, and Egypt that was almost invulnerable to barbarians based in Europe. Constantinople, too, proved exceptionally resistant to siege. The eastern empire thus managed to sustain relative prosperity in Asia and Egypt and to tap their wealth to maintain imperial rule (albeit with less security and prosperity) in the Balkans and even to restore it temporarily to Italy and North Africa. At least for time: when, in the seventh century, most of the wealthy provinces of Asia and Africa were lost to Persian and then to Arab empires, the east Roman state lost some 4/5 of its revenues [63]. Most of Italy fell to the Lombards, and the Balkans to Avars and Slavs.