The future of financial globalisation
http://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap69.htm
The BIS 11th Annual Conference took place in Lucerne, Switzerland on 21-22 June 2012. The event brought together senior representatives of central banks and academic institutions, who exchanged views on the conference theme of "The future of financial globalisation". This volume contains the opening address of Stephen Cecchetti (Economic Adviser, BIS), a keynote address from Amartya Sen (Harvard University), and the available contributions of the policy panel on "Will financial globalisation survive?". The participants in the policy panel discussion, chaired by Jaime Caruana (General Manager, BIS), were Ravi Menon (Monetary Authority of Singapore), Jacob Frenkel (JP Morgan Chase International) and José Dario Uribe Escobar (Banco de la Repubblica).
The papers presented at the conference and the discussants' comments are released as BIS Working Papers 397 to 400:
1 Financial Globalisation and the Crisis, BIS Working Papers No 397
by Philip R. Lane
Comments by Dani Rodrik
The global financial crisis provides an important testing ground for the
financial globalisation model. We ask three questions. First, did
financial globalisation materially contribute to the origination of the
global financial crisis? Second, once the crisis occurred, how did
financial globalisation affect the incidence and propagation of the
crisis across different countries? Third, how has financial
globalisation affected the management of the crisis at national and
international levels?
2 The great leveraging, BIS Working Papers No 398
by Alan M. Taylor
Comments by Barry Eichengreen and Dr. Y V Reddy
What can history can tell us about the relationship between the banking
system, financial crises, the global economy, and economic performance?
Evidence shows that in the advanced economies we live in a world that is
more financialized than ever before as measured by importance of credit
in the economy. I term this long-run evolution "The Great Leveraging"
and present a ten-point examination of its main contours and
implications.
3 Global safe assets, BIS Working Papers No 399
by Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas and Olivier Jeanne
Comments by Peter R Fisher and Fabrizio Saccomanni
Will the world run out of 'safe assets' and what would be the
consequences on global financial stability? We argue that in a world
with competing private stores of value, the global economic system tends
to favor the riskiest ones. Privately produced stores of value cannot
provide sufficient insurance against global shocks. Only public safe
assets may, if appropriately supported by monetary policy. We draw some
implications for the global financial system.
4 Capital Flows and the Risk-Taking Channel of Monetary Policy, BIS Working Papers No 400
by Valentina Bruno and Hyun Song Shin
Comments by Lars E O Svensson and John B Taylor
This paper examines the relationship between low interests maintained by
advanced economy central banks and credit booms in emerging economies.
In a model with crossborder banking, low funding rates increase credit
supply, but the initial shock is amplified through the "risk-taking
channel" of monetary policy where greater risk-taking interacts with
dampened measured risks that are driven by currency appreciation to
create a feedback loop. In an empirical investigation using VAR
analysis, we find that expectations of lower short-term rates dampen
measured risks and stimulate cross-border banking sector capital flows.
Erskine Bowles, who is sort of a Democrat, met Wednesday with House Speaker John Boehner to help Republicans promote proposals to cut entitlements, as part of the “fiscal cliff” negotiations.
This is the right place for Bowles, who has long maintained a mutual-admiration society with House Budget Committee chairman Paul Ryan, R-Wisconsin. The former Clinton White House chief of staff has always been in the corporate conservative camp when it comes to debates about preserving Social Security, Medicare and Medicaid.
It’s good that he and Boehner have found one another. Let the
Republicans advocate for the cuts proposed by Bowles and his former
Wyoming Senator Alan Simpson, his Republican co-conductor on the train wreck that produced the so-called “Simpson-Bowles” deficit reduction plan.
After all, despite the media hype, Simpson-Bowles has always been a non-starter with the American people.
Last summer, at the Democratic and Republican national conventions,
so many nice things were said about the recommendations of the National
Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and Reform that had been chaired by
former Wyoming Senator Alan Simpson, a Republican, and Bowles that it
was hard to understand why they were implemented. Paul Ryan went so far
as to condemn President Obama for “doing nothing” to implement the
Simpson-Bowles plan—only to have it noted that Ryan rejected the
recommendations of the commission.
But, while a lot of politicians in both parties say a lot of nice
things about the austerity program proposed by Simpson-Bowles, there is a
reason why there was no rush before the election to embrace the
blueprint for cutting Social Security, Medicare and Medicaid while
imposing substantial new tax burdens on the middle class.
It’s a loser.
Before the November 6 election, Simpson and Bowles went out of their way to highlight the candidacies of politicians who supported their approach—New Hampshire Republican Congressman Charlie Bass, Rhode Island Republican US House candidate Brendan Doherty, Nebraska Democratic US Senate candidate Bob Kerrey. Bipartisan endorsements were made, statements were issued, headlines were grabbed and…
The Simpson-Bowles candidates all lost.
Americans are smart enough to recognize that Simpson-Bowles would stall growth. And they share the entirely rational view of economists like Paul Krugman.
“Simpson-Bowles is terrible,” argues Krugman, a Nobel Prize winner
for his economic scholarship. “It mucks around with taxes, but is
obsessed with lowering marginal rates despite a complete absence of
evidence that this is important. It offers nothing on Medicare that
isn’t already in the Affordable Care Act. And it raises the Social
Security retirement age because life expectancy has risen—completely
ignoring the fact that life expectancy has only gone up for the well-off
and well-educated, while stagnating or even declining among the people
who need the program most.”
On election night, Peter D. Hart Research Associates surveyed Americans with regard to key proposals from the commission. The reaction was uniformly negative.
By a 73-18 margin,
those polled said that protecting Medicare and Social Security from
benefit cuts is more important than bringing down the deficit.
By a 62-33 margin,
the voters who were surveyed said that making the wealthy start paying
their fair share of taxes is more important than reducing tax rates
across the board (62 percent to 33 percent).
But that’s just the beginning of an outline of opposition to the Simpson-Bowles approach.
To wit:
* 84 percent of those surveyed oppose reducing Social Security benefits;
* 68 percent oppose raising the Medicare eligibility age;
* 69 percent oppose reductions in Medicaid benefits;
* 64 percent support addressing the deficit by increasing taxes on
the rich—with more than half of those surveyed favoring the end of the
Bush tax cuts for those making more than $250,000.
Americans want a strong government that responds to human needs:
• 88 percent support allowing Medicare to negotiate with drug companies to lower costs;
• 70 percent favor continuing extended federal unemployment insurance;
• 64 percent support providing federal government funding to local governments;
• 72 percent say that corporations and wealthy individuals have too much influence on the political system.
AFL-CIO president Richard Trumka is right. On November 6, “The American people sent a clear message.”
With their votes, with their responses to exit polls, with every
signal they could send, the voters refused to buy the “fix” that Erskine
Bowles is selling.